Use of the Power Resources Approach to Trade Unions in Transformation
Use of the Power Resources Approach to Trade Unions in Transformation
By: Bhakti Ram Ghimire, Advocate
By: Bhakti Ram Ghimire, Advocate
(LL.M-TU, Master in Industry and Employment Relation-ITCILO, Turin, Italy)
Introduction
Power resource theory is a political
theory which proposes the idea that the distribution of power
between major classes is to some extent accountable for
the successes and failure of various political ideologies. It argues that
"at its core, it asserts that working class power
achieved through organisation by labor unions or left parties, produces more egalitarian distributional outcomes".
Pioneered in the
1960s and 70s through the works of Walter Korpi, Gosta Esping-Andersen, and John Stephens,
the power resource theory is a method of approach utilized to examine the
characteristics and varying levels of impacts of social policies as well as
social inequalities on advanced industrialized nations. The power resources approach attempts to
account for the various approaches to social policy adopted by nations,
predominately focusing on the role and strength of labor
mobilization to gather a more encompassing explanation for the
varying levels of development and efficiencies of social policies. Therefore,
the power resource theory “helps to account for the emergence and development
of institutions”
and the varying “empowered actors attempting to generate differential
distributions of rewards.” This is a result of the varying policy
preferences of different social classes.
While the power
resource theory is arguably the most successful theory in explaining the
variations in development and efficiencies of social protection systems and
institutions among developed democracies, there are criticisms that point out
the lack of accountability for factors such as variations in “coverage,
extension, and generosity among welfare states” in addition to not accounting
for the importance of political mobilization based
on social class. Competing theories have also challenged PRT with
alternative explanations for the varying levels of welfare development such as
the importance of employers and cross-class alliances that exist in coordinated
market societies.
A Brief
History of the Power Resources Approach
The origins of
the Power Resources Approach (PRA) in the late 1960s and early 1970s with the
re-discovery of class as an analytical category and as a mobilising and
organising principle among left scholars and social activists. The re-emergence
of industrial conflict as well as the rise of the New Left and the student
movement had shattered the “end of ideology thesis” challenging the hegemony of
pluralism, neo corporatism and orthodox Marxism. Although the growth of class
theory was a global phenomenon, the form it took was shaped by the different
historical and social contexts. In
Europe, Walter Korpi (1974, 1983) was a pioneer in demonstrating that the
conflicts of interest manifested in the political arenas of the European
welfare state could be seen as a form of democratic class struggle. In the
United States (US), Erik Olin Wright introduced a sophisticated version of
Marxist class theory and was to become a key figure in developing the PRA.
Another more implicit influence on the power resources approach stems from
social movement studies in the United States. Similar to the concept of power
resources, the resource mobilisation approach assumes that mobilisation depends
on movements’ access and ability to accumulate collective resources and to
utilise those resources in collective action[1].
Class theory and worker agency came to the fore in the semi-industrialised
countries of the Global South in the 1970s and 1980s. A new worker militancy
and a new form of unionism emerged that went beyond collective bargaining and
actively engaged in political and community issues. These unions challenged
authoritarian rule and the lack of social infrastructure in the working-class
communities of countries such as Brazil, South Africa, the Philippines and
South Korea. This new wave of worker militancy was labelled social movement
unionism as it blurred the demarcation between unions as formal organisations
and social movements as loosely structured networks of action[2].
In the 1990s the concept of social movement unionism was to travel northwards
where it was used to describe union revitalisation in the United States[3].
At this time, organised labour in most developed countries was in decline. With
the rise of globalisation and the growing precarisation and in-formalisation of
work, the overall context had changed dramatically since the late 1970s[4].
Trade union density (the share of union members of the overall workforce)
dropped fast. For instance, between 1980 and 2000 in the United States it fell
from 20.9 per cent to 11.9 per cent, while in France it plummeted from 18.3 per
cent to only 7 per cent[5]. It was in this context that a second wave of
the discussion on labour power started and the basic concept of the PRA was
created by Erik Olin Wright (2000) and Beverly Silver (2003). Two concepts –
structural power as the power stemming from labour’s position in the economic
system, and associational power arising from collective political or trade
union workers’ associations laid the foundation for the discussion on the
sources of labour power. In the following decade, scholars from different world
regions added conceptual innovations to the approach. The concept of symbolic
power was added into the power resources approach by researchers in the United
States and the Global South[6],
arguing that workers with limited structural power were able to compensate for
the lack of associational power “by drawing upon the contested arena of culture
and public debates about values”[7].
Following a similar line of reasoning, researchers from South Africa argued
that workers in the informal sector are able to mobilise logistical power
instead of structural power through street blockades or other forms of joint
action by trade unions together with social movements[8].
Researchers from Germany discussed the role of institutions for labour power,
arguing that organised labour can draw upon institutional power resources such
as institutionalised labour rights and institutionalised dialogue procedures,
sources of power that labour can rely on even when structural and associational
power is weakened[9]. In
addition to these debates on the nature of labour power, scholars from Canada
argued that specific capabilities are needed to mobilise the individual power
resources[10].
Taken together, this discussion led to a vast body of divergent varieties of
the PRA, thereby further developing single power resources or exploring how
these sources of power are interconnected.
1. Structural
Power
Structural power refers to the position of
wage earners in the economic system. It is a primary power resource as it is
available to workers and employees even without collective interest
representation. It arises “out of the type of dependencies between the social
parties at the place of work” and also on the labour market. Structural power
rests on the power to cause disruption (disruptive power) and as such to
interrupt or restrict the valuation of capital.[11]
Workplace bargaining power and marketplace bargaining power are
the two forms of structural power.
Workplace
bargaining power depends on the status of workers and employees in the
production process. It is mobilised by the refusal to continue working, in
addition to strikes and demonstrations, can also encompass covert forms of
industrial conflict such as sabotage or go-slows.[12]
This means that workplace bargaining power is sometimes exercised decent rally
or spontaneously. By stopping work, wage earners can cause major costs for
capitalists and force them to offer better remuneration or working conditions. Wage-earners
in sectors with high labour productivity, highly-integrated production
processes or in important export branches have a particularly high degree of
workplace bargaining power as local work stoppages have an impact that goes far
beyond the work of just those on strike.[13]
Workplace bargaining power is hotly contested however capital tries to restrict
workplace bargaining power by relocating production sites, changing the way
production is organised or through rationalisation measures.[14]
Conversely, wage earners sometimes secure their power position by influencing
the reorganisation and innovation process by lobbying the government or
creating tripartite institutions (government, employers and trade unions) on
economic and technology politics.
Workplace
bargaining power is not only exercised in the direct production process, but
also at other points in the capital cycle. For instance, wage earners (in the
transport sector, for example) have circulation power or logistical power which
can slow the circulation of capital and labour via certain transport routes or
distribution channels. Circulation power can for instance be mobilised by
street blockades of social groups who are not wage-earners (e.g. informal self-employed
workers).[15] Employees
working in the field of care and education, in nurseries, nursing or private
homes exercise reproduction power by disrupting the ability of other workers to
perform their wage-earning work and as such influence other sectors of the
economy. Reproduction power often has contradictory effects. In some cases wage
earners cannot cause high costs for employers (e.g. in public education). Also,
they have to convince the “customers” (e.g. the parents of the children in a
playschool) of the legitimacy of their demands for higher wages and better
working conditions.
Marketplace bargaining power is the
second form of structural power. It is the product of a tight labour market and
as such the “possession of rare qualifications and skills demanded by employers,
low unemployment” and the “ability to fully withdraw from the labour market and
to live off other sources of income”.[16]
Marketplace bargaining power is exercised subtly and is only felt indirectly.
Employees can simply change their job without fearing unemployment when
marketplace bargaining power is high, thereby producing extra training costs
and a loss of production for the employers, for instance. To prevent this,
higher wages are paid. Marketplace bargaining power varies depending on the
structure of the labour market or in other words its segmentation into core
workforces, those in vulnerable employment, the unemployed and other groups.
Government intervention and regulation also imposes limits on the labour
market, for instance through immigration policy, and influences the marketplace
bargaining power of wage earners.[17]
The limits set are often tightened further by ethnic and gender-specific
division lines or actually even enabled by these in the first place. The
overall result is that staggered hierarchies prevail between individuals and
groups of wage earners. These hierarchies arising from the varying level of
resources the wage earners have at their disposal and the limits imposed on the
labour market also harbour the negative risk of stripping workers of their
sense of solidarity for each other. Such divides become clear in particular in
the informal sector in the Global South: informal workers have limited
workplace and marketplace bargaining power, while the powerful and relatively
well paid workers in major industrial companies and are often considered to
enjoy a privileged position.
What is required to successfully apply
structural power, is the skill to optimally combine structural power with
organisational capacities in the existing institutional setting and to develop
an effective conflict and strike strategy. Conflicts can be dealt with more
efficiently by deploying the weapon of striking in a targeted way instead of
using it repeatedly without any real effect. Historically, changes in the
accumulation of capital have always also influenced workplace and marketplace
bargaining power.[18]
The
introduction of Fordist assembly line work, for instance, meant that individual
industrial workers could interrupt the production process virtually at the
touch of a button. This influenced the trade unions’ power to act. The decline
of the American and of most European trade unions starting in the 1970s was apparently
to the dwindling structural power of wage earners. Not only did relocations and
the focus on shareholder value undermine their workplace bargaining power, the
supply-side economic policies of governments like those of Thatcher (1979),
Reagan (1981) and Kohl (1982), following the neoliberal watershed, contributed
to cementing mass unemployment. In the age of flexible capitalism, in many
countries the divides on the labour market between the core workforces and
vulnerable groups on the margins have become ever deeper. Together with new
approaches of “activating labour market policies” (workfare) these trends have
reduced the marketplace bargaining power of the wage earners. However, there
are countervailing global trends to be seen as well. For instance, the
relocations away from the centres of global capitalism have contributed in some
countries of the Global South (China, South East Asia, Mexico) and also Eastern
Europe to the emergence of new worker milieus with a high degree of workplace
bargaining power.
2. Associational Power
Associational
power arises “from workers uniting to form collective political or trade union
workers’ associations”.[19]
It pools the primary power of labourers and employees and can even compensate
for a lack of structural power “without fully replace it however”.[20]
In contrast to structural power, this requires an organisational process to
take place and collective actors to emerge who are capable of producing and
executing strategies.[21]
Erik Olin Wright distinguishes between three levels at which such actors come
into play at the workplace and as such in connection with workplace bargaining
power, there are works groups or works councils. At the sectorial level and as
such closely connected to marketplace bargaining power, trade unions are the
major players. Finally, in the political system and as such in connection with
societal power it is above all workers’ parties that represent the interests of
wage earners. The relationship of the individual levels to one another may
undergo historical shifts: decentralized groups at local level may gain
influence if the umbrella associations at the national level are weakened, for
instance. Above the levels described there are also other trade union actors at
the supranational level (for instance in the form of global union federations)
acting transnationally and supporting wage earners above all in countries with
weak organisational or institutional resources.[22]
Member numbers are usually cited as a reliable
indicator for determining associational power. Karl Marx was already aware of
the fact that the “social power of the workmen” lay in the “force of numbers”.[23]
In spite of the great variations in the significance and relevance of
membership of trade unions from country to country, the following trend does
apply as a result - the higher the degree of unionisation in individual
sectors, the stronger the works councils and the higher the number of members
of workers parties, the higher the probability that they will successfully
represent the wage-earners. Trade unions play a special role: because they offer
the possibility of overarching coordination, larger than individual workplaces
and autonomous representation of interests, which can counteract weak
representation in the political system.[24]
Associational power is not based solely on the number of members though. Other
factors are also of crucial significance.[25]
Infrastructural
resources: trade unions require material and human resources to be able to
carry out their work. By material resources we mean the financial capacity of a
trade union. This consists – alongside a full-to-the-brim strike fund amassed
from reserves – of buildings for meetings, training and offices and regular
income. Human resources are also important. Trade unions are not only reliant
on the work of full-time staff (and exemption from work for works council
members and active trade unionists on the shop-floor), they also need to pool
certain staff capabilities to be successful. This includes technical specialist
staff, scientific research institutes, education establishments and above all
experienced volunteers and permanent staff.
Organisational
efficiency: to exert associational power, efficient organisational
structures are necessary. Only then can trade unions deploy their
infrastructural resources effectively and conduct work action. An efficient
organisational structure implies an efficient division of labour in the
organisation, established and functioning working processes and a sensible
distribution of resources.[26]
Member participation: in addition to
the “wiliness to pay”, union members also need to demonstrate a “willingness to
act” and play an active role in measures such as strikes, campaigns and in the
internal discussion process.[27]
If the union full-time staff are not representative of the grass roots members,
this can be an obstacle.[28]
Participation can only be ensured if the relationship between active trade unionists
and “normal” members is based on a well-established “system of expectations and
accomplishments”.[29]
The relationship between member participation and organisational efficiency is
not one of simple correlation.[30]
Without active participation, the trade union turns into a bureaucratic
organisation, whilst a very high level of member participation is difficult to
sustain and may in the long run undermine efficiency.
Internal cohesion: finally,
associational power also builds on solidarity between trade union members.[31]
The existence of a collective identity plays a key role in this. It is formed
through close-knit social networks, shared everyday experiences and ideological
common ground. Internal cohesion in the organisation is crucial to be able to
conduct industrial action successfully, overcome crisis situations and to
pursue political projects. However, collective identities of workers transform
as social milieus change. This means that internal cohesion does not just grow
automatically with the emergence of new “homogenous” working classes, it needs
to be renewed constantly through activities and actions on the part of the
organisation in order to cope with changing collective identities and social
milieus.
To effectively
harness their own associational power, the structures of the associations have
to be optimised so that associational action can be reconciled with the
underlying structural conditions and the interests of the members.
Organisational flexibility can be enhanced by various strategies such as
organising new member groups, deliberate and targeted reallocation of
resources, changing the staff structure with a new generation of staff, new
forms of member participation or “salient knowledge” i.e. specific local,
biographical knowledge and skills.[32]
The decline of the US and many European trade
unions was expressed most saliently through its dwindling associational power.
The declining membership numbers attest to this in particular. This in turn led
to the trade unions’ infrastructural resources shrinking. With the weakening of
the traditional working class milieu in countries such as the US, France,
Germany and the UK the internal cohesion of the organisations was also
weakened; many members were less willing to get active and become involved. A
low representation of groups such as precarious and female workers as a result
of major social trends like casualization, feminisation of work or the rise of
the service economy also contributed to this development. Only few individual
trade unions in industrial countries such as Germany have been able to defy
this decline by changing their organisational structures and recruiting new
groups of members.[33]
However, in some countries of the Global South, new trade union movements have
been emerging since the 1980s (South Africa, Brazil, South Korea, South East
Asia etc.). This had a great deal to do with the growing industrial sectors in
these countries, which allowed them to recruit trade union members with a high
degree of workplace bargaining power, who later also engaged in democracy
movements, too (for instance in Brazil and South Africa).[34]
3. Institutional
Power
Institutional
power is usually the result of struggles and negotiation processes based on
structural power and associational power. Such institutions, which as “a secondary
form of power” constitute “a coagulated form of the two other primary forms of
power” often result as a concession or event as an attempt at cooperation on
the part of capital towards the workforce.[35]
New institutions usually arise at the end of combative cycles of the labour
movement, historical-political breaks with the past (de-colonialisation) or
were implemented when capital was dependent on the labour movement’s willingness
to cooperate.[36]
Institutional power is of a two-fold nature whilst from time to time it may
grant trade unions far-reaching rights, at the same time it restricts their
power to act. The relationship between strengthening and weakening labour
rights is always the product of a unique, one-off power balance between capital
and labour which has bee “solidified” in co-determination institutions.[37]
In the national system of industrial relations, struggles and agreements agreed
in the past still echo today the dual interest representation in Germany (works
councils at the level of the workplace and trade unions at industry-wide level)
originates, for instance, out of the compromise struck between the classes
during the post-war period, whilst the historical centrality of state
regulation is still felt in the major strike movements in modern-day France.[38]
The dual nature of institutional power brings with it the challenge of reconciling
the “two faces of unionism”[39]
– the focus on grassroots and the movement on the one hand, and institutional
representation of interests on the other, or mediating between the “logic of membership” and the
“logic of influence”.[40]
It comes down to the ability to use institutions to one’s own ends through
lobbying and by exhausting the legal possibilities available, whilst at the
same time remaining politically autonomous.
If this is not successful, unions risk
scenarios such as representation gaps or a loss of influence over daily
politics. Containment of class conflict leads to their “institutional isolation”.[41]
This means that conflicts are separated from their political content, banished
to the economic sphere and dealt with inside individual institutions. This
produces specific action routines by collective actors, for instance by trade
unions, employer associations and works councils. Here, the type of
institutional regulation is key.[42]
There are different types such as legal guarantees (freedom of association, the
right to strike etc.), the legal institutional framework (labour courts, etc.),
decision-making competences in individual policy fields (economics, labour
market etc.) and the collective bargaining system or workplace representation
(co-determination, health and safety etc.). Thus, the institutionalisation of
class conflict goes hand in hand with its fixation in law and the emergence of
different levels of institutional power. These are the same levels at which
associational power is exercised and class compromises are forged: a) the
political system; b) the arena of collective bargaining; and c) the workplace.[43]
Here, too, institutional power resources have developed at the supranational
level, as a result of ILO social and labour standards, for instance, which can
play a role in disputes at the national level. Transnational trade union actors
usually aim to mobilise and harness the institutional resources at various
different levels.
The unique feature of institutional power is
its steadfastness over time. It is rooted in the fact that institutions lay
down basic social compromises transcending economic cycles and short-term
political changes. Trade unions can even still use institutional power
resources if their associational and structural power is shrinking. One key
question therefore is how stable institutionalised resources are. There are
different time horizons that apply here: sometimes they are extremely
far-reaching, as they like the freedom of association are considered
untouchable privileges with constitutional standing or have been enshrined by
supranational regimes. Other institutional resources are also very stable as
they constitute legal rules and as such can only be altered by going through
parliament and legal procedures. There are, however, more fragile agreements.
Many corporatist alliances are based on (tripartite) institutionalised dialogue
procedures and can be rescinded rather easily.[44]
Consequently, institutional power does not last forever. There are three ways
it can be weakened:
(1) Underlying
economic conditions: changes in these also impact institutional power
resources. The focus on shareholder value and relocations have undermined the
workplace bargaining power of workers and contributed to works councils mainly
having to negotiate wage cuts and job losses in this environment.[45]
(2) Behaviour
on the part of capital: For institutional procedures to work, the trade unions
must be accepted as authentic representatives of employee interests by capital
associations and governments. This means that if associational power declines
there is the danger they will withdraw from dialogue procedures or that
institutions will continue to exist as mere rituals.[46]
(3) Attack on
institutional power: This changes the institutional basis of wage earner power.
The best-known example of such counter-reforms is Thatcherism, which eroded
British labour law to such an extent that the ILO now talks of a “limited right
to strike”.
Institutional power has remained rather
steadfast in many countries though. For instance, the German case is
characterised by the fact that the institutional structure has remained largely
intact from a formal point of view, but that since the 1980s, the underlying
economic conditions and the behaviour on the side of capital has changed.
Dwindling workplace bargaining and associational power of the wage earners
contributed to the slow erosion of the institutional structure of dual interest
representation, rendering the negotiation processes between capital and labour
increasingly asymmetrical.[47]
Conversely, it can also be very difficult to enshrine new institutional power
resources: the Brazilian central-left governments of “Lula” da Silva and
Rousseff (2003-2016), for instance, faltered at the hurdle of fundamentally
reforming the labour legislation that had been in place for roughly 70 years.
But there are also historical situations in which radical changes do occur. In
the wake of the euro crisis a rigid austerity policy was institutionalised at
the European level, which in Southern Europe in particular has gone hand in
hand with massive interference in collective bargaining autonomy, labour market
reforms and the restriction of employee rights.[48]
4. Societal
Power
By societal power we mean the latitudes for
action arising from viable cooperation contexts with other social groups and
organisations, and society’s support for trade union demands. The exercise of
societal power is essentially a question of the ability to assert hegemony that
is to say to generalise the political project of the trade unions within the
prevailing power constellation so that society as a whole adopts it as its own.
This entails a deliberate departure from the level of the workplace and opening
up the trade union’s social environment as a battlefield.[49]
There are two sources of societal power
– coalitional power and discursive power. These two power resources are
mutually reinforcing. Coalitional power means having networks to other social
actors at one’s disposal and being able to activate these for mobilisations and
campaigns.[50]
Essentially they involve pursing common goals and entering into mutual
commitments. Coalitional power is thus based on boosting one’s own associational power by harnessing
the resources of other players or on the trade union receiving support from
these actors. Relevant literature cites social movements, social associations,
NGOs, students and churches as typical allies.[51]
Such coalitions can only work, however, if there are bridge builders'[52]people
who are equally rooted in the trade union and non-trade union context – and if
alliances go beyond selective, occasional cooperation. Coalitional power can be
harnessed in workplace disputes by affording employees support in the dispute
they are involved in locally. Protests and joint initiatives can also allow
trade unions to exert pressure in the political system. These types of
coalitions range from local alliances against the privatisation of the water
supply all the way to transnational protest networks against free trade and
investment agreements such as the movement against TTIP (Transatlantic Trade
and Investment Partnership).
Effective exercise of societal power is also
“expressed by being able to successfully intervene in public debates on
historically established underlying hegemonic structures of the public sphere”[53]
and in doing so to assume the role of opinion leader on trade union-related
issues. Achieving a high degree of discursive power is subject to many
preconditions. It builds on trade union issues being perceived as just by the
general public, and this power is particularly potent “if the feeling of being
treated unjustly amongst the workforce coincides with perceptions of reality
shared by broad sections of society”.[54]
If moral ideas of legitimacy or the “moral economy”[55]
are being undermined, the trade unions can build public pressure. This happens
above all through scandalisation of injustices, with trade unions waging
classification battles over which working conditions are considered unfair.[56]
This in turn, enables them to then influence the prevailing norms themselves.
The discursive power of trade unions is only
effective, however, if it is in line with prevailing views of morality. These
have developed historically and are embedded in everyday thinking by stories,
myths and beliefs. Trade unions thus have specific narrative resources
available to them that they can deploy to exercise discursive power.[57]
They usually relate to struggles and fixed standards that are rooted in society’s consciousness. Such narrative
resources may vary in terms of how pronounced they are depending on the
organisation and cultural context in question. From resisting Apartheid in
South Africa all the way to the “golden age” of Fordism, relationships and
references can be built to politicise feelings of unjust treatment.
Furthermore,
trade unions also need to offer credible interpretation patterns or “frames”
and solutions to problems and present these to the public. They usually refer
here to the successes they have achieved through their work. The
problem-solving ability of the trade unions is important to actually be able to
deploy their own narrative resources in the first place, as otherwise the
organisations lack credibility. This ability also contributes to renewing
narrative resources, which would otherwise lose their mobilisation power,
dismissed as “old hat”, which in turn would lead to the trade unions losing
their appeal. A pronounced problem solving ability contributes to political
opponents accepting trade unions as a negotiation partner or in a situation of
confrontation to fearing them as an adversary. Public perception of the trade
unions is thus key. If they are seen as defenders of just causes, their social
influence will increase. For discursive power it is therefore a matter of trade
unions providing patterns for interpreting or “frami” burning issues. The
ability to frame problems is all about strategically and intelligently
developing and using the societal power of the organisation. This means taking
the initiative at the right time and selecting the right issues for social
debates and mobilisations.[58]
If the trade unions fail to produce new patterns of interpretation to make
these politically effective, the foundations of their coalitional and
discursive power quickly crumble and in turn the opportunity to deploy them in
the battle for hegemony.
Changes in the underlying conditions also
change the societal power of the trade unions. Structural economic
transformation can disintegrate their social environment and erode their
coalitional power. Discursive power, too, can be weakened by “factual
constraints”. In many European countries and in the US, the discursive power of
the unions fell relatively continuously as of the late 1970s. In the 1990s in
particular, trade unions were increasingly perceived as outmoded reform saboteurs
and “naysayers” who had no real alternatives to offer in the age of
globalisation and the IT boom. The trade unions also had problems finding new
cooperation partners. Not only were their own social milieus crumbling, new
social movements like the green, neighbourhood,
women’s and human rights movements had
little in common with traditional trade union work, and in fact even tried to
distance themselves from them. Conversely, the social movement unionism in many
countries of the Global South (South Korea, etc.) was based on successful
cooperation with social movements; there are also positive cases of an increase
in discursive power. In the context of the economic crisis in 2008/9, for
instance, German trade unions were able to influence the crisis management
policy of the Federal Government to the benefit of large groups of employees
and as a result were celebrated as skilled crisis managers by the public.[59]
The brief presentation of the power resources
approach implies that specific skills are needed to mobilise the individual
resources. Some scientists have discussed different capabilities and capacities
in order to clarify how power resources can be used strategically.[60]
Christian Levesque and Gregor Murray (2010) for instance differentiate between
four capabilities: a) intermediation, i.e. developing a collective interest
(consensus building) out of conflicting demands both from within and outside of
the union; b) framing, i.e. developing the discourse and formulating (new)
strategies by defining a proactive and autonomous agenda within a larger
context; c) articulation; i.e. constructing multi-level interaction and
understanding, linking the local and the global across space; and d) learning
capabilities; i.e. fostering the ability to learn and to diffuse learning
throughout the organisation. Using insights from the past that can be applied
to the present and considered for the future. In addition to these four
capabilities there can be added organisational flexibility, i.e. adapting
organisational routines and traditions to reflect and support changes in the
policy needs as a fifth capability. The capabilities are related to power
resources. Some are linked to specific power resources, and others are more
generic. For instance, learning capabilities and articulation are quite
generic. Learning capabilities strengthen all other power resources and
capabilities, while articulation is crucial in bridging different levels of
union action and power resources. Other capabilities are closely related to a
specific power resource: Framing is helpful in developing societal power and
organisational flexibility is crucial in stengthening associational power.
Labour Power
in the Global Context
The
applicability of the power resources approach is not just limited to the
reality of the countries of the Global North. In fact, its conceptualities mean
it can be applied to a wide range of contexts.[61]
The structural power of the workers and employees arises from the specific
incorporation of a country into global capital accumulation, for instance. This
means that individual groups of workers in semi-peripheral and peripheral
countries are often particularly able to assert themselves as they occupy key
positions in the economy, whilst equally there are large groups of informally
employed people whose structural power is very limited. Strong trade unions in
the transport sector (ports, etc.) can often cause huge damage to economies
specialised in the export of resources and enforce their demands very
effectively.[62] This
means as a consequence that the power resources of wage earners in the global
capitalist system are unevenly distributed and structured with major ramifications
for trade unions. Institutional power on the other hand results largely from
the institutional system of the individual countries the institutional power
resources in states with corporatist labour relations (Argentina, Germany,
Japan, etc.) are very pronounced whilst wage-earners in countries with
regulatory patterns geared towards free market principles (Chile, Great
Britain, US) often have fewer resources. These varying constellations in turn
structure the power of the individual trade unions to act. It is similar when
it comes to societal power, which is always the product of the specific set of
actors, norm expectations and public discourses in a society. This means
ultimately that when taking strategic action, trade unions are dependent on deploying
their resources in such a way that the country specific context is harnessed in
an optimum way. It is not a matter of using all resources equally, but rather
finding the right mix for the specific problem scenario. And here, too, the
trade union players always have a strategic choice.
Labour Power
and Power Resources
The following
conceptualisation of power resources draws on these experiences. It adds two
further power resources, institutional power and societal power, to the
original sources of labour power as introduced by Wright (2000) and Silver
(2003). The relationship between the four power resources is complex, sometimes
conflicting, and not to be understood simply as an add-on.[63]
Furthermore, it is hardly possible for unions to advance all power resources at
the same time. Therefore, it is not so much the extent of power resources, but
rather their development and specific combinations which are crucial for
unions’ assertiveness. In the following, we outline key features of the
approach coupled with examples of their application. The PRA is founded on the
basic premise that the workforce can successfully defend its interests by
collective mobilisation of power resources in the structurally asymmetric and
antagonistic relationship between capital and labour. This notion builds on Max
Weber’s definition of power which is understood as “the probability that one
actor within a social relationship will be in a position to carry out his own
will despite resistance”. Thus, labour power is perceived first and foremost as
the power to do something (power to) and not as power to determine the rules of
play (power over).[64]
Labour power can be mobilised through different sources of power or power
resources, but its use is always embedded in social relationships and power
relations. This has two implications. First, the PRA needs to be understood as
a relational concept, as employers are able to mobilise power resources to
disorganise or come to an agreement with organised labour. Second, the primary
concern of the power resources approach is not only to analyse structural power
relations of this kind, but rather to understand the ability of wage earners to
assert their interests within the given general context. In other words, labour
power can be used in specific historical phases to significantly alter these
societal structures; the main objective of the PRA is to analyse the spaces of
action of trade unions and employees under given circumstances.
[1]
McCarthy, J.D. and M.N. Zald (1977) Resource Mobilization and Social Movements:
A Partial Theory. American Journal of Sociology, 82(6): 1212–41.
[2]
Webster, E. (1988) The Rise of Social Movement Unionism: The Two Faces of the
Black Trade Union Movement in South Africa. In State, Resistance, and Change in
South Africa, edited by P.H. Frankel, N. Pines and M. Swilling. London and New
York: Croom Helm.
[3]
Lipsig-Mumme, C. and E. Webster (2012) Reconnections: Labour Sociologies in a
Globalising Era. In Sociology Today: Social Transformations in a Globalising
World, edited by A. Sales. London: Sage.
[4]
Munck, R. (2002) Globalisation and Labour: The New “Great Transformation”.
London: Zed Books.
[5]
Mayer, G. (2004) Union Membership Trends in the United States.
https://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/cgi/
viewcontent.cgi?article=1176&context=key_workplace (accessed 28 May 2017).
[6]
Bezuidenhout, A., C. Bischoff and N. Nthejane (2017) Is COSATU still a
Working-class Movement? In Labour Beyond COSATU: Mapping the Rupture in South
Africa’s Labour Landscape, edited by A. Bezuidenhout and M. Tshoaedi.
Johannesburg: Wits University Press.
[7]
Chun, J.J. (2005) Public Dramas and the Politics of Justice. Comparison of
Janitors’ Union Struggles in South Korea and the United States. Work and
Occupations, 32(4): 486–503.
[8]
Webster (2008) Social Movement Unionism: Questions and Possibilities. Employee
Responsibilities and Rights Journal, 20(4): 309–13.
[9]
Dörre, K., H. Holst and O. Nachtwey (2009) Organizing – A Strategic Option for
Trade Union Renewal? International Journal of Action Research, 5(1): 33–67.
[10]
Lévesque, C. and G. Murray (2010) Understanding Union Power: Resources and
Capabilities for Renewing Union Capacity. European Review of Labour and
Research, 16(3): 333–50.
[11] Piven, F.F. (2008) Challenging Authority: How
Ordinary People Change America. Plymouth, MS: Rowman & Littlefield.
[12]
Brinkmann, U., H.L. Choi, R. Detje, K. Dörre, H. Holst, S. Karakayali and C.
Schmalstieg (2008) Strategic Unionism: Aus der Krise zur Erneuerung? Umrisse
eines Forschungsprogramms. Wiesbaden: Springer.
[13]
Silver, B.J. (2003) Forces of Labor. Workers’ Movements and Globalization since
1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[14]
Harvey, D. (1990) The Condition of Postmodernity: An Inquiry into the Origins
of Cultural Change. Cambridge: Blackwell.
[15]
Webster, E. (2015) Labour after Globalization. Old and New Sources of Power. In
Labour and Transnational Action in Times of Crisis, edited by A. Bieler, R.
Erne, D. Golden, I. Helle, K. Kjeldstandli, T. Matos and S. Stan. Lanham, MD:
Rowman & Littlefield.
[16]
Silver, B.J. (2003) Forces of Labor. Workers’ Movements and Globalization since
1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[17]
Carr, E.H. (1968) Nationalism and After. London: Macmillan.
[18]
Silver, B.J. (2003) Forces of Labor. Workers’ Movements and Globalization since
1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[19]
Brinkmann, U. and O. Nachtwey (2010) Krise und strategische Neuorientierung der
Gewerkschaften. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, 13–14: 21–29.
[21]
Silver, B.J. (2005) Forces of Labor. Workers’ Movements and Globalization since
1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[22]
Wright, E.O. (2000) Working-class Power, Capitalist-class Interests and Class
Compromise. American Journal of Sociology, 105(4): 957–1002.
[23]
Marx, K. (1974) Political Writings, Volume 3. New York: Vintage Books.
[24]
Deppe, F. (1979) Autonomie und Integration. Materialienzur
Gewerkschaftsanalyse. Marburg: Verlag Arbeiterbewegung und
Gesellschaftswissenschaft.
[25]
Lévesque, C. and G. Murray (2010) Understanding Union Power: Resources and
Capabilities for Renewing Union Capacity. European Review of Labour and
Research, 16(3): 333–50.
[26]
Behrens, M., R. Hurd and J. Waddington (2004) How Does Restructuring Contribute
to Union Revitalization? In Varieties of Unionism. Strategies for Union
Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy, edited by C.M. Frege and J.E. Kelly.
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
[27]
Offe, C. and H. Wiesenthal (1980) Two Logics of Collective Action: Theoretical
Notes on Social Class and Organizational Form. Political Power and Social
Theory, 1(1): 67–115.
[28]
Lévesque, C., G. Murray and S. Queux (2005) Union Disaffection and Social
Identity, Democracy as a Source of Union Revitalization. Work and Occupations,
32(4): 400–22.
[29]
Beaud, S. and M. Pialoux (1999) Retour surla condition ouvrière. Enquête aux
usines Peugeot de Sochaux-Montbéliard. Paris: Fayard.
[30]
Voss, K. (2010) Democratic Dilemmas: Union Democracy and Union Renewal.
Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 16(3): 369–82.
[31]
Hyman, R. (2001) Understanding European Trade Unionism: Between Market, Class
and Society. London: Sage.
[32]
Ganz, M. (2000) Resources and Resourcefulness: Strategic Capacity in the
Unionization of Californian Agriculture, 1959–1966. American Journal of
Sociology, 105(4): 1003–62.
[33]
Schmalz, S. and M. Thiel (2017) IG Metall’s Comeback: Trade Union Renewal in
Times of Crisis. Journal of Industrial Relations, 39(4): 465–86.
[34]
Silver, B.J. (2003) Forces of Labor. Workers’ Movements and Globalization since
1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[35]
Brinkmann, U. and O. Nachtwey (2010) Krise und strategische Neuorientierung der
Gewerkschaften. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, 13–14: 21–29.
[36]
Schmalz, S. and N. Weinmann (2016) Between Power and Powerlessness: Labor
Unrest in Western Europe in Times of Crisis. Perspectives on Global Development
and Technology, 15(3): 543–66.
[37]
Poulantzas, N. (1978) State Theory: Political Superstructure, Ideology,
Authoritarian Statism. London: Verso.
[38]
Artus, I./ Holland, J. (2013): Von der Belebung des toten Ritters in seiner
Rüstung: Coalition building und Gewerkschaftsproteste in Frankreich. In:
Schmalz, S./Dörre, K. (eds.): Comeback der Gewerkschaften? Machtressourcen,
innovative Praktiken, internationale Perspektiven, Frankfurt/New York, pp.
131-147
[39]
Webster, E. (1988) The Rise of Social Movement Unionism: The Two Faces of the
Black Trade Union Movement in South Africa. In State, Resistance, and Change in
South Africa, edited by P.H. Frankel, N. Pines and M. Swilling. London and New
York: Croom Helm.
[40]
Schmitter, P. C./ Streeck, W. (1981): The Organization of Business Interests: A
Research Design to Study the Associative Action of Business in the Advanced
Industrial Societies of Western Europe. Discussion Paper: IIM/LMP 81/13.
[41]
Dahrendorf, R. (1959): Class and Class Conflict in Industrial Society.
California, Stanford.
[42]
Müller-Jentsch, W. (1997) Soziologie der industriellen Beziehungen: Eine
Einführung. Frankfurt am Main and New York: Campus.
[43]
Wright, E.O. (2000) Working-class Power, Capitalist-class Interests and Class
Compromise. American Journal of Sociology, 105(4): 957–1002.
[44]
Haipeter, T. (2012): Sozialpartnerschaft in und nach der Krise: Entwicklungen
und Perspektiven. In: Industrielle Beziehungen 19, pp. 387–411.
[45]
Massa-Wirth, H. (2007): Zugeständnisse für Arbeitsplätze?: Konzessionäre
Beschäftigungsvereinbarungen im Vergleich Deutschland – USA. Berlin.
[46]
Ramsay, H. (1977): Cycles of Control: Worker Participation in Sociological and
Historical Perspective. In: Sociology, 11: pp. 481–503.
[47]
Dörre, K. (2010): Überbetriebliche Regulierung von Arbeitsbeziehungen. In:
Böhle, F. G./ Voß, G./ Wachtler, G. (eds.), Handbuch Arbeitssoziologie.
Wiesbaden, pp. 873–912.
[48]
Schulten, T./ Müller, T. (2013): A new european interventionism? The impact oft
he new European governance on wages and collective bargaining, in Natali, D./
Vanhercke, B. (Eds.): Social Developements in the European Union 2012.
Brussels: ETUI, pp. 181-214.
[49]
Lévesque, C. and G. Murray (2013) Renewing Union Narrative Resources. How Union
Capabilities Make a Difference. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 51:
777–96.
[50]
Frege, C. M./ Kelly, J. E. (eds.) (2004): Varieties of unionism: Strategies for
union revitalization in a globalizing economy. Oxford /New York.
[51]
Frege, C. M./ Kelly, J. E. (eds.) (2004): Varieties of unionism: Strategies for
union revitalization in a globalizing economy. Oxford /New York.
[52]
Brecher, J./ Costello, T. (1990): Building bridges: The emerging grassroots
coalition of labor and community. New York.
[53]
Urban, H.-J. (2013): Der Tiger und seine Dompteure: Wohlfahrtsstaat und
Gewerkschaften im Gegenwartskapitalismus. Hamburg.
[54]
Haug, W. F. (2009): Gewerkschaften im High-Tech-Kapitalismus vor der Hegemoniefrage.
In: Das Argument, 51, pp. 879–893.
[55]
Thompson, E. P. (1971): The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the
Eighteenth Century. In: Past & Present, 50, pp. 76–136.
[56]
Chun, J. J. (2009): Organizing at the margins: The symbolic politics of labor
in South Korea and the United States. Ithaca.
[57]
Lévesque, C./ Murray, G. (2013): Renewing Union Narrative Resources. How Union
Capabilites Make a Difference. In: British Journal of Industrial Relations, 51,
pp. 777-796.
[58]
Snow, D. A./ Soule, S. A./ Kriesi, H. (eds.) (2004): The Blackwell companion to
social movements. Malden.
[59]
Schmalz, S./ Weinmann, N. (2016): Between Power and Powerlessness: Labor Unrest
in Western Europe in Times of Crisis. In: Perspectives on Global Development
and Technology 15(3): pp. 543-566.
[60]
Ganz, M. (2000) Resources and Resourcefulness: Strategic Capacity in the
Unionization of Californian Agriculture, 1959–1966. American Journal of
Sociology, 105(4): 1003–62.
[61]
Julián Vejar, D. (2014) Legados del momento socialista en Chile: Una mirada al
sindicalismo en los gobiernos de Lagos y Bachelet (2000-2010). Teoria &
Sociedade, 22(1): 118–40.
[62]
Bergquist, C. W. (1986): Labor in Latin America. Comparative Essays on Chile,
Argentina, Venezuela, and Colombia, Stanford.
[63]
AK Strategic Unionism (2013): Jenaer Machtressourcenansatz 2.0. In: Schmalz,
S./Dörre, K. (eds.): Comeback der Gewerkschaften? Machtressourcen, innovative
Praktiken, internationale Perspektiven, Frankfurt/New York, pp. 345-375.
[64]
Lévesque, C./ Murray, G. (2010): Understanding union power: resources and
capabilities for renewing union capacity. In: Transfer: European Review of
Labour and Research, 16, pp. 333–350.
Comments
Post a Comment